Poverty and Social Welfare in Great Britain from 1598
Top Introduction (JPN) Introduction (ENG) List of Pictures List of Bibliographies


アイコンをクリックすると画像にリンクします。閲覧にはDjVuプラグインが必要です。
印刷機能は DjVu プラグインのものをご使用ください。
Click the following icons to link the pictures. DjVu plugin is required.

Pictures
1704
GIVING ALMS NO CHARITY; DANIEL DEFOE'S
SEMINAL CONTRIBUTION TO THE GREAT NATIONAL DEBATE
ON PROVISION FOR THE POOR
012. [DEFOE, Daniel.] Giving alms no charity, and employing the poor a grievance to, the nation, being an essay upon this question, whether work-houses, corporations, and houses of correction for employing the poor, as now practis' d in England; or parish-stocks, as propos'd in a late pamphlet, entituled, A bill for the better relief, employment and settlement of the poor, etc. Are not mischievous to the nation, tending to the destruction of trade, and to encrease the number and misery of the poor. Addressed to the parliament of England. London. Printed, and sold by the booksellers of London and Westminster. 1704. 4to. ,[2],3-28p. Rebound in half calf, marbled boards, vellum tips. An excellent copy.

MOORE 88. HANSON 446; KRESS 2419; GOLDSMITHS 4104. L, ReU; CaOHM, CLU-C, DFo, InU-Li, MB, MH, MH-BA, NjP, NIC, NNC in ESTC.

Daniel Defoe's Giving Alms no charity, 1704, is one of the most important and significant pamphlets ever issued on the treatment of the poor in Great Britain.

The idea of "putting the Poor to work" had dominated the thinking of philanthropists and those concerned with social welfare in the last quarter of the seventeenth century. William III repeatedly suggested to the House of Commons that if "you can find proper means of setting the poor at work, you will ease yourself of a very great burden, and at the same time add so many useful hands to be employed in our manufactures and other public occasions." In 1704 there were no fewer than four Bills in Parliament designed to put the ideas thus sanctioned into operation. One of these - the one mentioned by De Foe on his title page - was drawn up by the great capitalist entrepreneur of the day, Sir Humphrey Mackworth. This met with almost universal acceptance. The measure would have set up in each parish something like the "Publick Workhouse" of Sir Matthew Hale and Sir Josiah Child, the "working almshouse or hospital" advocated by Thomas Firmin and John Locke, in which, on materials and working capital raised by the Poor Rate, all paupers able to work, whaterver their age or sex, would have been offered employment for wages. If they refused they would have lost their right to any relief and probably become liable to commitment to a House of Correction. At the eleventh hour the project was killed dead by Daniel De Foe who addressed to Parliament the telling pamphlet Giving Alms no charity. In 1705, at a later period of the same session of Parliament, the House of Lords threw out Sir Humphrey Mackworth's Bill; and no similar measure has afterwards got anything so close to success.

What Daniel De Foe threw into the discussion was the hardest possible stone of economic disillusionment and worldly cynicism. He struck down at a blow the compassionate efforts of those who he no doubt regarded as soft-hearted dupes of their sentiments of pity.

In this pamphlet De Foe gives classic expression of the idea that intervention by government in economic processes can be pernicious and harmful. Providing funds to pay the poor to work steals employment from the rest of the working community and in so doing undermines and distorts the true economy. In addition De Foe was forthright in seeing poverty as often the fault of the poor and blaming the increase of poverty on a deterioration of morals and an increase in idleness and extravagance. In De Foe's opinion "'tis the Men that won't work, not the Men that can get no work, which makes up the numbers of our Poor."

The idea of putting the poor to work was echoed in every succeeding generation. A hundred years later, Coleridge and Southey, for example, were again urging that employment be created as an antidote to distress. But whenever this happened De Foe's voice echoed with equal and opposite force. The potency of De Foe's idea and the effectiveness of his presentation of it are reflected in the fact that it was reading Eden, and in Eden, Defoe's attack on public employment which helped to change Malthus's mind on the poor law itself. In the 1798 edition of An Essay on the Principles of Population Malthus did not urge the abolition of the Poor Law altogether, but the establishment of a new national workhouse scheme. By 1803 when the much expanded quarto edition of his work came out he had read Eden and De Foe and the text of his work was changed to include a condemnation of Workhouses and employment. All public employment, he repeated, by competing with the private, merely maintained a pauper by putting a free labourer out of employment. With the abandonment of the workhouse scheme came the famous plan for the abolition of the Poor Law altogether.

De Foe, like Hanway after him, emphatically asserted that the strength of a nation consisted in its population. Speaking of Elizabeth the Ist he says: "This wise Queen knew that the numbers of inhabitants are the Wealth and Strength of a Nation.." In consequence he was not opposed to an influx of immigrants, for example those fleeing religious persecution in other parts of Europe, especially, if, as was often the case, they were skilled craftsmen, tradesmen or merchants.

In addressing the problem of poverty De Foe is keen to make clear that he does not consider England itself poor. On the contrary, thanks to the success of trades and manufactures since the time of Elizabeth, "we are as Rich a Nation as any in the World." The problem was that, rich though we were, we were "burthen'd with a crowd of clamouring, unimploy'd, unprovided for poor People..."

De Foe argued that "There is in England more Labour than Hands to perform it, and consequently a want of people, not of employment. " He would not admit that any man who really wanted work would fail to find it: "No Man in England, of sound Limbs and Senses, can be Poor meerly for want of Work." It follows that there should be no such thing as begging: "So that begging is a meer scandal in General, in the Able 'tis a scandal upon their industry, and in the Impotent 'tis a scandal upon the Country." In other words since work is available the able-bodied have no need of begging and should be ashamed to do it. The disabled or sick should have proper provision through the parishes and never be put in the position of needing to beg. In this case the charity which gives to beggars or vagrants is a mistaken one, it encourages begging and does more harm than good. If beggars can so easily get a good living by begging, why should they work? "As for the craving Poor, I am perswaded I do them no wrong when I say, that if they were incorporated they would be the richest Society in the Nation." True Elizabeth I brought in statutes against able-bodied beggars etc. but these laws have not been sufficiently enforced: "...had they been severely put in Execution by our Magistrates, 'tis presumed these Vagrant Poor had not so encreas'd upon us as they have."

De Foe then proceeds to an attack on the make-work schemes. It is the job of the poor to find work for themselves not for society to find work for them. The provision of Workhouses in De Foe's view tended to encrease the numbers of the Poor and not to relieve them. If poor children are put to work making Bays in London there is less work for other poor families to do elsewhere: "For every piece of Bays so made in London there must be a Piece the less made in Colchester." "But to set Poor people at Work, on the same thing which other poor People were employed on before, and at the same time not encrease the Consumption, is giving to one what you take away from another, enriching one poor Man to starve another, putting a Vagabond into an honest Man's Employment."

De Foe here seems to take the view that the market for goods is, after all, a finite one and to have somewhat forgotten his former argument that there was not so much a shortage of work as a shortage of hands to do it. More work to do than hands to do it suggests a surplus of demand: there was, it seems, however no such surplus. Had there been there would have been room, possibly, for the normal economy and make- work schemes to tap the unexploited potential.

De Foe was no doubt correct in pointing out the harmful effects of artificially creating employment but perhaps wrong, in wanting to place the blame for poverty on the poor themselves, in stating there was no such thing as genuine unemployment.

De Foe makes it clear that his pamphlet is in no way concerned with the sick, the infirm the aged or the disabled: "These as infirmities meerly Providential are not at all concerned in this Debate; ever were, will, and ought to be the Charge and Care of the Respective Parishes..." The existence of the able-bodied poor he puts down firmly to their laziness, extravagance, improvidence and predilection for drink and in so saying, returns to his former theme "Tis the Men that wont work, not the Men that can get no work, which makes up the numbers of our Poor..."

As has been elsewhere pointed out De Foe offers no real solution to the problem of the poor. His achievement was the negative one of successfully demolishing Mackworth's scheme for workhouses. It set the tone for all those who, to this day, suspect that all poverty is largely the fault of the poor and who stress the harmful effects of state or charitable provision.